找回密码
 立即注册
查看: 656|回复: 0

巴菲特:商誉及其摊销:规则与现实

[复制链接]
发表于 2016-8-2 10:58:10 | 显示全部楼层 |阅读模式
这篇附录探讨的只是经济和会计商誉,而不是日常所说的声誉。比如,一个公司可能被大多数客户喜欢,甚至热爱,但是却不具有任何经济商誉。(AT&T在分拆前总的来说声誉很好,但没有一分钱的经济商誉。)遗憾的是,一个公司可能被其客户所不喜欢,但却具有大量,而且不断增长的经济商誉。所以,就目前而言,让我们先忘掉感情,只关注于经济和会计。
当一个公司被并购时,会计准则要求并购价格首先分配给所并购的可确认资产的公允价值。资产的公允价值总和(经过扣除负债后)经常是少于公司的并购总价格。在这种情况,这两者的差异就被分配到一个资产帐户,称为“超出并购的净资产权益的额外成本”。为了避免不断的重复这一很长的说法,我们将用“商誉”来替代之。
在1970年11月前购买公司所产生的商誉有不同的处理。除非在极少的情况下,只要仍然持有所购买的公司,商誉就可以存在于资产负债表上。这意味着不需针对盈利核算摊销费用而逐渐削减这项资产。
但是1970年以后的并购就不同了。当并购产生商誉,这些商誉必须在不超过40年的时间里进行摊销。每年以相等的摊销费用减少利润帐户。由于40年是所允许的最长时间,这也是管理层(包括我们自己)通常选用的。这项减少利润的年度费用不允许被用来抵扣税,所以具有一般费用大约两倍的税后收入影响。
这就是会计商誉的做法。为了揭示这与经济商誉实际情况的不同,让我们看一个手头的例子。我们将近似一些数字,并极大的简化,以让这个例子容易理解。我们还将提及一些对投资者和经理人的影响。
Blue Chip Stamps于1972年初以2500万美元购买了喜诗糖果。当时,喜诗有大约800万的净有形资产。(在整个讨论中,应收帐款将被归于有形资产,这个定义对商业分析是适合的。)这个水平的有形资产,除了季节性的短时期,当时足够不用债务而运营业务。喜诗当时的税后盈利是200万美元,这似乎保守的代表了以1972年美元计的未来盈利能力。
因此,我们学到的第一课:当净有形资产能产生远超过市场水平的回报率时,公司价值从逻辑上讲,远超过净有形资产。这一超出市场回报的价值被资本化就变成了经济商誉。
在1972年(和现在)相对来说只有很少的公司能像喜诗那样稳定的获得25%的税后净有形资产回报率。而且这种回报率还是建立在保守的会计方式和没有财务杠杆的情况下。并不是公允市场价值的库存,应收款,或者固定资产,产生了这种非凡的回报率。正好相反,是无形资产的组合,尤其是在消费者中良好的声誉产生了这一切。这种良好的声誉是建立在消费者对其产品以及公司员工无数愉快的体验之上。
这种声誉创造出了一个消费者特许经营权。这让产品对购买者的价值,而不是产品的生产成本,成为了决定销售价格的主要决定性因素。消费者特许经营权是经济商誉的主要来源。其他的来源包括无盈利管制的政府特许经营权,如电视台和在一个行业的低成本生产者的持久地位。
让我们回到喜诗这个例子的会计处理。BlueChip对喜诗的并购超出了净有形资产1700万美元。这就要求在BlueChip的资产负债表上设立同等额度的商誉帐户,并在40年的时间里,每年把这项资产摊销42.5万美元的费用,随之减少利润。到了1983年,经过了11年这样的摊销,这1700万已经被减少到了1250万。伯克希尔,与此同时,拥有60%的BlueChip,所以也就是60%的喜诗。这一所有权意味着伯克希尔的资产负债表反映了60%的喜诗的商誉,即750万美元。
1983年伯克希尔并购了BlueChip余下的股份。这一合并要求使用并购会计处理,而不是一些合并所允许的“合并”会计处理。在并购会计处理下,我们给(或“支付”)Blue Chip的股份的“公允价值”必须在我们从BlueChip获得的净资产上分摊。这一“公允价值”的多少,当上市公司用股票进行并购时总是用所放弃的市场价值来衡量。
“并购”的资产包括了Blue Chip所拥有的所有东西的40%(如上所示,伯克希尔一直拥有余下的60%)。当伯克希尔“支付”的超过了我们收到的5170万美元可确认净资产,这一超出的部分被分配到两部分商誉:2840万美元在喜诗,以及2330万美元在Buffalo
所以在并购后,伯克希尔有了喜诗的商誉,具有两部分:从1971年并购所剩下的750万美元,以及1983年的40%“并购”所新创造的2840万美元。我们在未来28年的摊销费用将是每年100万美元,之后的12年也就是2002到2013年是每年70万美元。
换句话说,不同的并购日期和价格,让我们对同样一个资产有了两个非常不同的价值和摊销费用。(我们重复我们的免责声明:我们没有更好的会计系统可以建议。必须被解决的大量问题令人难以想象,因此必须有硬性的规则。)
但是,经济现实是什么?一个实际情况是,从喜诗并购后每年从利润表中作为成本扣除的摊销费用并不是真正的经济成本。我们知道喜诗去年在2000万美元的净有形资产之上,挣了1300万美元的税后利润。这一业绩表明现存的经济商誉远高于最初总的商誉会计成本。换句话说,虽然会计商誉从并购那一刻就有规律的定期减少,但经济商誉却以不规律但却非常重大的方式增加。
另一个现实是,未来的年度摊销费用将无法符合经济成本。当然,喜诗的经济商誉也可能消失。但商誉不会稳定的消耗,或者以类似稳定的方式消耗。最有可能的是,商誉将会增加。由于通胀的作用,商誉将会以目前的美元价值,而不是以不变美元价值计增加。
这一可能性的存在是因为真实的经济商誉倾向于随通胀在名义价值上成比例增加。为了说明这是如何运作的,让我们把喜诗这样的业务和一个更普通的业务做一个对比。1972年,当初我们并购喜诗时,它在8百万美元净有形资产之上的盈利是2百万美元。让我们假定我们假设的普通业务也有2百万美元的盈利,但却需要1800万美元的净有形资产来维持正常运营。在必须的有形资产之上只获得11%的回报,这个普通的业务具有很少,或者没有经济商誉。
这样一个业务,完全有可能因其净有形资产而以1800万美元卖出。与之相反,我们支付了2500万美元购买了喜诗,即使它没有更多的盈利,而且只有前面普通业务不到一半的实打实的资产。难道少既是多,就像我们的并购价格所暗示的那样?答案是“对”。即便两个业务都预期有停滞的业务量,只要你预计到了一个持续通胀的世界,正如我们在1972年预计的那样,这个答案就是“对”。
要理解为什么,想象物价水平翻倍之后对这两个业务的影响。这两者都需要把名义盈利翻倍到4百万美元才能赶得上通胀。这似乎不需要太多的手段:只要卖同样多的数量,把价格翻倍就行了,假设利润率不变,盈利一定翻倍。
但是关键的是,为了达到这一点,两者恐怕都必须把正常的净有形资产投资翻倍。因为这就是通胀常常强加于商业的经济要求,有好处也有坏处。以美元计的销售额翻倍意味着更多的钱必须马上被用在应收款和库存。固定资产所用的钱对通胀会有较慢的反应,但肯定会有反应。而且,所有这些通胀要求的投资将无法改善回报率。这种投资的原因在于维持业务的生存,而不是拥有者利益的增长。
记住,喜诗只有800万美元的净有形资产。所以,它只需要投入额外的800万美元来支持通胀所强加的资本需求。而普通的业务,则有着两倍的负担,需要1800万美元的额外资本。
尘埃落定之后,这个普通的业务,现在每年盈利400万美元,可能仍然价值相当于其有形资产价值,即3600万美元。这意味着所有者投资的每一个美元,只产生了一个美元的名义价值增加。(这与他们把钱加到存款帐户中一样,都是一美元对一美元。)
喜诗同样也盈利4百万美元,用我们购买时同样的估值方法评估(逻辑上应该如此)可能价值5000万美元。所以喜诗获得了2500万美元的名义价值增加,而所有者仅仅投入了800万美元的额外资本,这相当于每投入1美元获得超过3美元的名义价值。
记住,即使是这样,喜诗的拥有者也由于通胀被迫付出800万美元的额外资本,这也才仅仅是维持真实利润。任何不用杠杆而且需要一些净有形资产来运营(几乎所有的业务都是如此)的业务都会被通胀伤害。只需要很少有形资产的业务只不过受的伤害最少。
然而这个事实,当然一直很难被许多人领悟。多年以来,传统智慧,(长于传统,短于智慧)认为充满天然资源,工厂,机器和其他有形资产(“我们信赖的商品”)的业务能够提供最好的通胀保护。其实根本不是这样。重资产的业务通常获得低回报率,低到仅能提供足够的资本来满足现存业务的通胀下需求,而根本无法剩下任何东西来支持真正的增长,分配股息给所有者,或者并购新的业务。
与之相反,不成比例的大量商业财富在通胀时期积累起来。这些财富是通过拥有一些业务运营而实现的,这些运营结合了具有持久价值的无形资产与相对很少的有形资产需求。在这些例子里,名义盈利大幅增加,这些资金可以用来并购其他的业务。这种现象在通讯行业尤为明显。这一行业仅需要很少的有形资产投资,但是却能保持特许经营权。在通胀时期,商誉是不断奉献的礼物。
但是这一论断自然只适用于真正的经济商誉。欺骗性的会计商誉(有很多这样的例子)是另外一码事。当一个过度兴奋的管理层用愚蠢的高价购买一个业务时,前面描述的同样的会计细节也能被观察到。因为它无处可去,愚蠢的买价最终留在商誉帐户。考虑到由于缺乏管理纪律而创造的这样一个帐户,在这种情况下,应该称之为“无誉”。无论期限,通常可以观察到40年的仪式性摊销。管理层追求刺激的肾上腺素被资本化保留在帐面上作为一项“资产”,就好像这个并购是一个明智的举动。
如果你坚持相信对商誉的会计处理是衡量经济现实的最佳方式,我建议你思考最后一个例子。
假设一个公司有每股20美元的净资产,全部是有形资产。进一步假设公司内部发展了一个绝妙的消费者特许经营权,或者这个公司足够幸运,获得了一些重要的FCC最初授予的电视台许可。所以,这个公司于有形资产上盈利丰厚,比如每股5美元,或者25%的回报。
有这样的经济状况,这支公司的股票可能卖价每股100美元或更高。而且还有可能在一个谈判卖出整个业务中获得如此的价格。
假设一个投资者支付了每股100美元购买股票,实际上是用每股80美元支付了商誉(正如一个企业并购整个公司时那样)。这个投资者是否应该每年拿出2美元的摊销费用,用于计算“真实”每股盈利?如果是这样,新的3美元“真实”盈利是否应该促使他重新思考购买价格?
我们相信经理人和投资者应该从两个视角看待无形资产:
在分析运营结果,也就是评估一个业务单元的内在经济状况时,摊销费用应该被忽略。一个业务预期在净有形资产上所能获得的利润,除去任何商誉的摊销费用,才是衡量业务运营在经济上是否有吸引力的最佳指导。这也是衡量业务运营的经济商誉的当前价值的最佳指导。
在评估商业并购是否明智时,摊销费用也应被忽略。摊销费用既不应该从业务的盈利中减去,也不应该从业务的成本中扣除。这意味着永远视所购买的商誉为在任何摊销之前的全部成本。更重要的是,并购成本应该被定义为,包含所支付代价的全部内在商业价值,而不仅是其记录的会计价值,不论合并当时所涉及的证券的市场价格,也不管是否允许用合并会计处理。比如,我们在合并Blue Chip 40%的喜诗和Buffalo EveningNews的商誉时,真正支付的代价远超过我们记录在账面上的5170万美元。这种不一致的存在是由于在合并时,伯克希尔股票的市场价值低于其内在商业价值,对我们来说这才是决定真实成本的价值。
从视角(1)看似乎是赢家的业务运营,有可能从视角(2)看却黯然失色。一个好的业务不一定是一个好的并购对象,虽然好业务是寻找好并购的地方。
我们将寻求并购那些用(1)衡量是优秀的运营状况,而且用(2)衡量能产生合理回报的业务。会计后果将完全被忽略。
在1983年底,在我们会计帐面上的净商誉是6200万美元,包括7900万美元标明在资产负债表的资产一侧,以及1700万美元负的商誉以冲销我们持有的Mutual Savingsand Loan的权益价值。
我们相信净经济商誉远超过这6200万美元的会计数字。
----------------------------------------
本文由圈友:姜南雪 推荐
小编的话:放篇全英文的,以便更好的欣赏巴老的文采,有圈友会问,为什么中文英文不放在一起?这个问题应该问问腾讯,为啥微信要给个20000字的限制?昨天新闻哥发了个问题,如果饭店送错了饭,你会选什么:默默的吃掉or认为很好吃高兴的吃掉or发火让他重做,对于吃货小编来说毫不犹豫的会认为很好吃高兴的吃完,现在大家就高兴的对着看这篇分开的中英文章吧!
This appendixdeals only with economic and accounting Goodwill not the goodwill of everydayusage. For example, a business may be well liked, even loved, by most of itscustomers but possess no economic goodwill. (AT&T, before the breakup, wasgenerally well thought of, but possessed not a dime of economic Goodwill.) And,regrettably, a business may be disliked by its customers but possesssubstantial, and growing, economic Goodwill. So, just for the moment, forgetemotions and focus only on economics and accounting.
When a business ispurchased, accounting principles require that the purchase price first beassigned to the fair value of the identifiable assets that are acquired.Frequently the sum of the fair values put on the assets (after the deduction ofliabilities) is less than the total purchase price of the business. In thatcase, the difference is assigned to an asset account entitled "excess ofcost over equity in net assets acquired". To avoid constant repetition ofthis mouthful, we will substitute "Goodwill".
AccountingGoodwill arising from businesses purchased before November 1970 has a specialstanding. Except under rare circumstances, it can remain an asset on thebalance sheet as long as the business bought is retained. That means noamortization charges to gradually extinguish that asset need be made againstearnings.
The case isdifferent, however, with purchases made from November 1970 on. When thesecreate Goodwill, it must be amortized over not more than 40 years throughcharges of equal amount in every year  tothe earnings account. Since 40 years is the maximum period allowed, 40 years iswhat managements (including us) usually elect. This annual charge to earningsis not allowed as a tax deduction and, thus, has an effect on after-tax incomethat is roughly double that of most other expenses.
That howaccounting Goodwill works. To see how it differs from economic reality, letlook at an example close at hand. We l round some figures, and greatlyoversimplify, to make the example easier to follow. We l also mention someimplications for investors and managers.
Blue Chip Stampsbought See early in 1972 for $25 million, at which time See had about $8million of net tangible assets. (Throughout this discussion, accountsreceivable will be classified as tangible assets, a definition proper forbusiness analysis.) This level of tangible assets was adequate to conduct thebusiness without use of debt, except for short periods seasonally. See wasearning about $2 million after tax at the time, and such earnings seemedconservatively representative of future earning power in constant 1972 dollars.
Thus our firstlesson: businesses logically are worth far more than net tangible assets whenthey can be expected to produce earnings on such assets considerably in excessof market rates of return. The capitalized value of this excess return iseconomic Goodwill.
In 1972 (and now)relatively few businesses could be expected to consistently earn the 25% aftertax on net tangible assets that was earned by See doing it, furthermore, withconservative accounting and no financial leverage. It was not the fair marketvalue of the inventories, receivables or fixed assets that produced the premiumrates of return. Rather it was a combination of intangible assets, particularlya pervasive favorable reputation with consumers based upon countless pleasantexperiences they have had with both product and personnel.
Such a reputationcreates a consumer franchise that allows the value of the product to thepurchaser, rather than its production cost, to be the major determinant ofselling price. Consumer franchises are a prime source of economic Goodwill.Other sources include governmental franchises not subject to profit regulation,such as television stations, and an enduring position as the low cost producerin an industry.
Let return to theaccounting in the See example. Blue Chip purchase of See at $17 million overnet tangible assets required that a Goodwill account of this amount beestablished as an asset on Blue Chip books and that $425,000 be charged toincome annually for 40 years to amortize that asset. By 1983, after 11 years ofsuch charges, the $17 million had been reduced to about $12.5 million.Berkshire, meanwhile, owned 60% of Blue Chip and, therefore, also 60% of See.This ownership meant that Berkshire balance sheet reflected 60% of SeeGoodwill, or about $7.5 million.
In 1983 Berkshireacquired the rest of Blue Chip in a merger that required purchase accounting ascontrasted to the "pooling" treatment allowed for some mergers. Underpurchase accounting, the "fair value" of the shares we gave to (or"paid") Blue Chip holders had to be spread over the net assetsacquired from Blue Chip. This "fair value" was measured, as it almostalways is when public companies use their shares to make acquisitions, by themarket value of the shares given up.
The assets"purchased" consisted of 40% of everything owned by Blue Chip (asnoted, Berkshire already owned the other 60%). What Berkshire "paid"was more than the net identifiable assets we received by $51.7 million, and wasassigned to two pieces of Goodwill: $28.4 million to See and $23.3 million toBuffalo Evening News.
After the merger,therefore, Berkshire was left with a Goodwill asset for See that had twocomponents: the $7.5 million remaining from the 1971 purchase, and $28.4million newly created by the 40% "purchased" in 1983. Ouramortization charge now will be about $1.0 million for the next 28 years, and$.7 million for the following 12 years, 2002 through 2013.
In other words,different purchase dates and prices have given us vastly different asset valuesand amortization charges for two pieces of the same asset. (We repeat our usualdisclaimer: we have no better accounting system to suggest. The problems to bedealt with are mind boggling and require arbitrary rules.)
But what are theeconomic realities? One reality is that the amortization charges that have beendeducted as costs in the earnings statement each year since acquisition of Seewere not true economic costs. We know that because See last year earned $13million after taxes on about $20 million of net tangible assets a performanceindicating the existence of economic Goodwill far larger than the totaloriginal cost of our accounting Goodwill. In other words, while accountingGoodwill regularly decreased from the moment of purchase, economic Goodwillincreased in irregular but very substantial fashion.
Another reality isthat annual amortization charges in the future will not correspond to economiccosts. It is possible, of course, that See economic Goodwill will disappear.But it won? shrink in even decrements or anythingremotely resembling them. What is more likely is that the Goodwill will increase  in current, ifnot in constant, dollars  because ofinflation.
That probabilityexists because true economic Goodwill tends to rise in nominal valueproportionally with inflation. To illustrate how this works, let contrast a Seekind of business with a more mundane business. When we purchased See in 1972,it will be recalled, it was earning about $2 million on $8 million of nettangible assets. Let us assume that our hypothetical mundane business then had$2 million of earnings also, but needed $18 million in net tangible assets fornormal operations. Earning only 11% on required tangible assets, that mundanebusiness would possess little or no economic Goodwill.
A business likethat, therefore, might well have sold for the value of its net tangible assets,or for $18 million. In contrast, we paid $25 million for See, even though ithad no more in earnings and less than half as much in "honest-to-God"assets. Could less really have been more, as our purchase price implied? Theanswer is "yes"  even if bothbusinesses were expected to have flat unit volume as long as you anticipated, as we did in 1972, a world of continuousinflation.
To understand why,imagine the effect that a doubling of the price level would subsequently haveon the two businesses. Both would need to double their nominal earnings to $4 millionto keep themselves even with inflation. This would seem to be no great trick:just sell the same number of units at double earlier prices and, assumingprofit margins remain unchanged, profits also must double.
But, crucially, tobring that about, both businesses probably would have to double their nominalinvestment in net tangible assets, since that is the kind of economicrequirement that inflation usually imposes on businesses, both good and bad. Adoubling of dollar sales means correspondingly more dollars must be employedimmediately in receivables and inventories. Dollars employed in fixed assetswill respond more slowly to inflation, but probably just as surely. And all ofthis inflation-required investment will produce no improvement in rate ofreturn. The motivation for this investment is the survival of the business, notthe prosperity of the owner.
Remember, however,that See had net tangible assets of only $8 million. So it would only have hadto commit an additional $8 million to finance the capital needs imposed byinflation. The mundane business, meanwhile, had a burden over twice as large  a need for $18 million of additional capital.
After the dust hadsettled, the mundane business, now earning $4 million annually, might still beworth the value of its tangible assets, or $36 million. That means its ownerswould have gained only a dollar of nominal value for every new dollar invested.(This is the same dollar-for-dollar result they would have achieved if they hadadded money to a savings account.)
See, however, alsoearning $4 million, might be worth $50 million if valued (as it logically wouldbe) on the same basis as it was at the time of our purchase. So it would havegained $25 million in nominal value while the owners were putting up only $8million in additional capital  over $3 ofnominal value gained for each $1 invested.
Remember, even so,that the owners of the See kind of business were forced by inflation to ante up$8 million in additional capital just to stay even in real profits. Anyunleveraged business that requires some net tangible assets to operate (andalmost all do) is hurt by inflation. Businesses needing little in the way oftangible assets simply are hurt the least.
And that fact, ofcourse, has been hard for many people to grasp. For years the traditionalwisdom long on tradition, short on wisdom held that inflation protection wasbest provided by businesses laden with natural resources, plants and machinery,or other tangible assets ("In Goods We Trust"). It doesn work thatway. Asset-heavy businesses generally earn low rates of return rates that oftenbarely provide enough capital to fund the inflationary needs of the existingbusiness, with nothing left over for real growth, for distribution to owners, orfor acquisition of new businesses.
In contrast, adisproportionate number of the great business fortunes built up during theinflationary years arose from ownership of operations that combined intangiblesof lasting value with relatively minor requirements for tangible assets. Insuch cases earnings have bounded upward in nominal dollars, and these dollarshave been largely available for the acquisition of additional businesses. Thisphenomenon has been particularly evident in the communications business. Thatbusiness has required little in the way of tangible investment  yet its franchises have endured. Duringinflation, Goodwill is the gift that keeps giving.
But that statementapplies, naturally, only to true economic Goodwill. Spurious accounting Goodwilland there is plenty of it around  isanother matter. When an overexcited management purchases a business at a sillyprice, the same accounting niceties described earlier are observed. Because itcan go anywhere else, the silliness ends up in the Goodwill account.Considering the lack of managerial discipline that created the account, undersuch circumstances it might better be labeled "No-Will". Whatever theterm, the 40-year ritual typically is observed and the adrenalin so capitalizedremains on the books as an "asset" just as if the acquisition hadbeen a sensible one.
If you cling toany belief that accounting treatment of Goodwill is the best measure ofeconomic reality, I suggest one final item to ponder.
Assume a companywith $20 per share of net worth, all tangible assets. Further assume thecompany has internally developed some magnificent consumer franchise, or thatit was fortunate enough to obtain some important television stations byoriginal FCC grant. Therefore, it earns a great deal on tangible assets, say $5per share, or 25%.
With sucheconomics, it might sell for $100 per share or more, and it might well alsobring that price in a negotiated sale of the entire business.
Assume an investorbuys the stock at $100 per share, paying in effect $80 per share for Goodwill(just as would a corporate purchaser buying the whole company). Should theinvestor impute a $2 per share amortization charge annually ($80 divided by 40years) to calculate "true" earnings per share? And, if so, should thenew "true" earnings of $3 per share cause him to rethink his purchaseprice.
We believemanagers and investors alike should view intangible assets from twoperspectives:
  • In analysis of operating results that is, in      evaluating the underlying economics of a business unit  amortization charges should be ignored.      What a business can be expected to earn on unleveraged net tangible      assets, excluding any charges against earnings for amortization of      Goodwill, is the best guide to the economic attractiveness of the      operation. It is also the best guide to the current value of the      operation economic Goodwill.


    • In evaluating the wisdom of business      acquisitions, amortization charges should be ignored also. They should be      deducted neither from earnings nor from the cost of the business. This      means forever viewing purchased Goodwill at its full cost, before any      amortization. Furthermore, cost should be defined as including the full      intrinsic business value not just the recorded accounting value of all      consideration given, irrespective of market prices of the securities      involved at the time of merger and irrespective of whether pooling      treatment was allowed. For example, what we truly paid in the Blue Chip      merger for 40% of the Goodwill of See and the News was considerably more      than the $51.7 million entered on our books. This disparity exists      because the market value of the Berkshire shares given up in the merger      was less than their intrinsic business value, which is the value that      defines the true cost to us.

Operations thatappear to be winners based upon perspective (1) may pale when viewed fromperspective (2). A good business is not always a good purchase although it agood place to look for one.
We will try toacquire businesses that have excellent operating economics measured by (1) andthat provide reasonable returns measured by (2). Accounting consequences willbe totally ignored.
At yearend 1983,net Goodwill on our accounting books totaled $62 million, consisting of the $79million you see stated on the asset side of our balance sheet, and $17 millionof negative Goodwill that is offset against the carrying value of our interestin Mutual Savings and Loan.
We believe neteconomic Goodwill far exceeds the $62 million accounting number.

回复

使用道具 举报

您需要登录后才可以回帖 登录 | 立即注册

本版积分规则

Archiver|手机版|小黑屋|徐星官网 ( 粤ICP备14047400号 )

粤公网安备 44030402005841号

GMT+8, 2024-12-27 05:27 , Processed in 0.022752 second(s), 18 queries .

Powered by Discuz! X3.4

Copyright © 2001-2021, Tencent Cloud.

快速回复 返回顶部 返回列表